Page 116 - Special Topic Session (STS) - Volume 4
P. 116

STS570 Nadim Ahmad et al.
                  country of the ultimate parent would be a logical alternative. Only the part of
                  value added with a physical presence, i.e. compensation of employees and
                  depreciation of non-IPP assets, possibly including a return on the investment,
                  would then remain in the countries in which the affiliates are located. Leaving
                  apart the relocation of IPPs and related depreciation, in a sense this treatment
                  would come down to an “upward shift” of distributed and reinvested earnings
                  from GNI to GDP.
                      16. From a conceptual point of view, the above treatment would also be
                  quite justifiable. IPPs are quite different from other types of fixed assets used
                  in the production of goods and services. Apart from having no physical and
                  local constraints, IPPs often concern the whole value chain, not a particular
                  part  of  the  production  process.  Often,  there  is  also  no  direct  link  to  the
                  production process, and also no direct link between today’s stock of assets
                  and today’s production of goods and services. IPPs often concerns results from
                  R&D, design, trademarks, etc., and once implemented they are easily scalable.
                  As such, there are very good reasons to consider IPPs as corporate assets, of
                  which the ultimate parent is indeed the true economic owner.
                      17. One complication may relate to the determination of the residence of
                  the ultimate parent. This does not necessarily coincide with the country in
                  which the formal holding of the MNE is located. Here, one can also observe
                  the phenomenon of corporate inversions, by setting up a holding type of SPE
                  to minimise tax burden. Having such a legalistic approach to the residence of
                  a parent, in combination with the above proposals for the treatment of SPEs
                  and IPPs would potentially lead to far more dramatic shifts of output and value
                  added from one country to another. Instead, one will have to determine the
                  “true” residence of the parent, on the basis of the location of the centre of
                  economic  decisions.  This  centre  would  typically  coincide  with  the  location
                  from where decisions are made on e.g. global arrangements of production,
                  R&D  and  other  corporate  investments,  corporate  finance,  appointment  at
                  senior management level, etc. It would therefore usually be the same location
                  as the one where the physical headquarters and the board of directors are
                          3
                  located.

                  4.  Discussion and Conclusion
                      18. It is clear that all of the above options require, at least to some extent,
                  the exchange of individual data on MNEs across countries. In the current legal
                  circumstances, this is a major  issue that would need to be resolved rather
                  urgently.  Two  possible  ways  forward  can  be  distinguished:  (i)  a  top-down
                  approach according to which data on MNEs are collected at the international


                  3  In some cases, two countries may share the headquarters of an MNE. Good examples are Royal
                  Dutch Shell and Unilever, which have part of their headquarters in the Netherlands and the
                  United Kingdom. In such cases, one may need to apply some proportionality rule.
                                                                     105 | I S I   W S C   2 0 1 9
   111   112   113   114   115   116   117   118   119   120   121