Page 413 - Special Topic Session (STS) - Volume 3
P. 413

STS552 Carol C. Bertaut et al.
                These findings have implications for understanding the factors influencing
            capital flows. For example, there has been much focus on the global impact of
            the  extraordinary  policy  actions  undertaken  by  advanced  economy  central
            banks in the wake of the global financial crisis. Of particular emphasis has been
            how these monetary policies spill over into emerging markets and how EME
            asset prices will react when these policies are reversed (Bowman et al 2015,
            Fratzscher et al 2018, Curcuru et al 2018). Our results showing understated
            growth in holdings of EME assets also imply mismeasurement of capital flows
            to  EMEs.  Overall,  flows  appear  to  have  been  stronger  when  policy  was
            especially  accommodative,  which  suggests  that  the  spillovers  may  be
            understated.
                Our results also weaken the argument that capital flows arising from foreign
            direct investment (FDI) are generally preferable because they are less volatile
            than portfolio flows, in part because FDI is harder to expropriate (Albuquerque
            2003) and is driven by pull rather than push factors (Eichengreen et al 2018).
            However, these arguments assume that portfolio flows in the BOP accounts fully
            capture investment in a country’s securities. When foreign residents buy bonds
            issued onshore, these purchases will show up as portfolio investment inflows.
            When corporations issue bonds via offshore affiliates, however, funds borrowed
            through the offshore entities are funnelled back to the parent firm in the form
            of lending or “reverse investment” in the parent firm. These flows, which will
            appear as FDI inflows, are effectively no different from typical portfolio flows,
            and can be just as volatile. Growing reliance on offshore financing vehicles for
            debt issuance can thus confound our understanding of the resilience of different
            types  of  cross-border  financial  flows.  Similarly,  our  results  also  raise  some
            potential  flags  for  interpreting  conclusions  on  the  effectiveness  of  capital
            controls  in  preventing  portfolio  inflows  to  emerging  markets  (Forbes  and
            Warnock 2012; Ahmed and Zlate 2014; Forbes et al. 2014; Forbes et al 2015;
            Pasricha et al. 2015). Foreign investors may still be able to gain exposures to
            countries via offshore-issued bonds, which typically are unaffected by controls.
            But  because  such  purchases  are  not  classified  as  portfolio  inflows  to  these
            countries, the effectiveness of the controls may be overstated.
                Our results are also relevant to the long-standing Lucas (1990) paradox,
            which  arises  from  differences  between  the  theoretical  prediction  of
            movements  between  developed  and  developing  countries,  and  what  is
            observed. Theory predicts that capital should move toward economies with
            lower levels of capital per worker. Contrary to this theory, most studies find
            that capital does not flow from more to less developed economies; rather, it
            flows in the other direction (see Alfaro et al. 2008, among others). Our results
            suggest that advanced economy exposure to EMEs is larger than previously
            believed, which resolves some portion of this puzzle. This is perhaps especially
            evident when we consider the global reaches of large multinational firms. In

                                                               402 | I S I   W S C   2 0 1 9
   408   409   410   411   412   413   414   415   416   417   418